DIRECT EXTRACTION OF CO2 FROM THE ATMOSPHERE. IS THIS REALISTIC? IF SO IT COULD BE A GAME CHANGER?
A
Swiss company has told the Carbon Brief website that there is a real prospect of reducing
the costs of the direct extraction of carbon dioxide from the atmosphere to a
point where it will be possible to consider large scale operations that could
substantially offset current emissions and even feature in attempts to reduce
concentration levels, in the so-called “zero carbon” or “net negative CO2”
policies that many people consider are implied in the Paris agreements. If
their promises are realistic, then this would be a truly revolutionary
development, with profound implications for our approach to climate policy. But
there will be a lot of questions to answer on the way.
A Swiss company has opened
what is believed to be the world’s first ‘commercial’ plant that sucks carbon
dioxide from the atmosphere, a process that could help reduce global warming,
it is claimed. The firm, Climeworks, expressed confidence they could bring down
the cost from $600 per tonne of the greenhouse gas to $200 in three to five
years with a longer term target of $100. This is almost an order of magnitude
lower than previous estimates of the cost of direct carbon extraction, widely
assumed to be around $1000 per tonne.
This is also one of the two
most important candidates for a game changing technology breakthrough that I
identified in my 2016 submission to the House of Lords Inquiry, which can be
viewed as a separate page on this site. If it proves to be feasible then it may
represent a considerable advance on what has hitherto been considered the only
feasible route to net negative carbon, the so-called bio-energy with carbon
capture and storage (BECCS) approach. Shortcomings of the latter include the
limited supply of bio-energy, not least due to land availability constraints,
and controversy over whether this really represents a sustainable approach[1]. So direct sequestration,
if feasible, is very attractive.
There are clearly still a
large number of outstanding questions before we get too excited by this
prospect.
Is $200 or $100 per tonne really
achievable? And if so is the technology scaleable? And to what scale[2]? If it is scaleable, it
seems likely the world could be seeking an expansion of the process well beyond
the 1% of current emissions suggested as an ambitious target by Climeworks.
The other big question is how
to dispose of the CO2 after its capture. This is a big issue, and a
very substantial part of the cost for all carbon capture technologies,
including those based on removing the CO2 from fossil fuel
combustion. This cost needs to be factored in and is bound to be a fairly
substantial element in the total. It does not appear to be included in the
Climeworks figures. Moreover the disposal issue, at scale, will raise its own
environmental and risk issues.
But if these questions can be
answered this could be a very significant technology advance. It is certainly not
the magic bullet that solves all problems, but it could have some important
consequences for the way we look at climate policies. Why?
First, one of the most
terrifying features of the climate change threat is the apparent
irreversibility of the processes involved. CO2 emissions are
cumulative. If they cannot be removed on any scale, then there is a real risk
of a future where the climate science starts to tell us there is no return. At this point priorities would take a
dangerous turn towards survival rather than the global idealism, or at least
hope, that underpins global agreements. But it is not just that dealing with a very
expensive problem is psychologically more attractive than coping with the
prospect of unavoidable catastrophe. Ability, in principle at least, to partially
reverse out of the worst consequences, puts a finite bound on the costs of making
the wrong policy choices. Inter alia it ought to increase the available policy
options.
Second, and more importantly, direct
sequestration has the potential to change the basis of policy in relation to
carbon pricing. I have previously commented on the weakness of traditional cost
benefit analysis (CBA) in this context. CBA fails to provide a basis for a
carbon price, and the failure is in large measure due to an impossible number
of uncertainties (in climate, geographical and economic impact) to which
probabilities cannot be assigned from any established base of knowledge. But if
we have a clear way of putting a cost on CO2 removal, then we have
at least a first approximation to a “true” cost of CO2 emissions.
This might inter alia provide a better justification for effective carbon
pricing, and even for global adoption of a “common” rate of carbon tax. It
could be a much more hard-edged approach than complex negotiations over carbon trading
schemes, which, as with the EU Emissions Trading Scheme, have so far failed to
deliver adequate carbon prices.
These are obviously early days
for direct extraction technologies, and we should avoid premature optimism, but
this could be an important part of the geo-engineering landscape to watch.
[1] One
of the reasons BECCS is controversial is that its justification requires
careful analysis of the entire chain of processes involved, starting with the
cultivation of the bio-crop and including any ecological or carbon related side
effects, as well as consideration of the alternative land uses for food
production or other purposes.
[2] Limits
to scale might be imposed, for example, by the availability of other input
chemicals to the extraction process. But the more serious limitations are likely
to be on disposal of the CO2 gas. A preferred route of extraction
might be capture of the carbon in a solid and inert form, such as calcium
carbonate, if this were possible.
No comments:
Post a Comment