A more urgent approach to climate issues is stirring again among US politicians and opinion formers. A recent FT article highlights apparent conflicts of approach, and the need to reconcile them. In part any conflict might be seen as just another illustration of the deep ideological divide between believers in the ability of unfettered markets to resolve all problems, and proponents of a much greater role for state intervention. The reality is that effective policy on mitigation of climate change will always demand a combination of coordinated actions at government level with the powerful incentives that economic instruments can provide. There is no single silver bullet. Markets won't work on their own, and we also need both effective action on infrastructure and focused regulation.
Martin Wolf is always worth
reading on economics and this remains true when he turns his attention to
climate issues (The US debate on climate change is heating up. FT, 19
February 2019). This recent article suggests that informed opinion in the US,
perhaps for the first time since the early days of the Obama administration, is
moving towards increasing recognition of the fact that the US, widely seen as a
laggard on climate related policies, cannot stand back from its global
responsibilities in relation to curbing emissions. The US, as a country, still
has the greatest historic responsibility for CO2 (the most
significant of the greenhouse gases), even though it has now been overtaken by
China on current emissions. It is also still close to the highest for current
per capita emissions, where it is matched only by a few countries such as
Australia (coal once again at the heart of the problem) and surpassed in the
oil states of the Middle East by countries such as a Saudi Arabia with a
notorious history of wasteful subsidies to energy consumption.
Data source: CDIAC (1751-2013)
and BP (2014-2015)
Wolf highlights two recent
announcements. The first is an “economists’ statement on
carbon dividends”, endorsed by 3,333 US economists, including four former
chairs of the Federal Reserve and 27 Nobel laureates. Its main elements are
·
a carbon tax starting at $40 a ton
·
combined with a “carbon dividend” approach to return the proceeds to US
citizens
·
border tax adjustments for the carbon content of imports and exports
· prices
to act as a substitute for unnecessary regulations.
This plan is also to be
proposed to "other leading greenhouse gas emitting countries".
Source: Union of Concerned
Scientists
|
The ideas per se
are not new. Most economists view emissions pricing as a necessary if not
sufficient part of any solution. Others have discussed carbon wealth fund, and
tax and dividend approaches. (The “Carbon wealth fund” tag links to three
earlier articles.) Helm and Hepburn[1] were early
proponents of border tax adjustments. But bringing them together as a
coherent package, and recognising the seriousness of the issue (where
economists have often been slow), is very welcome.
The
second announcement is the Green New Deal
proposed by a group of House Democrats, led by Alexandria Ocasio-Cortez. It is
a proposal to transform the US economy by moving to zero carbon sources for
power generation and upgrading all buildings to achieve maximum energy
efficiency. The approach is strong on regulatory intervention and
infrastructure investment, but ignores the incentive effects of prices and
markets. Activists vigorously oppose market-based mechanisms, emissions trading
and offsets. With even more Utopian fervour they also dismiss major technology
options such as carbon capture and storage, nuclear power, waste-to-energy and
biomass energy, when the selection of at least some of these options is at
least helpful, and very likely necessary for a low or zero carbon future.1. The starting point of $40 per tonne is too low on its own to incentivise much or most of the investments and behavioural. Moreover, signalling a profile of carbon prices rising over time runs in the opposite direction to the environmental value of emissions reduction, which ought to prioritise current emissions[2].
2. Inter alia a rising profile leads to the well-known Green Paradox[3], where fossil producers have an incentive to advance their production of the most polluting fuels.
3. Border
tax adjustments make a great deal of theoretical sense, but pose huge practical
and administrative issues in measuring carbon content. Given the existing
complexities of international trade, rules of origin, etc, and in the current
global trade environment, they could quickly fall into a tangled web of complex
negotiations and disputes.
4. The major
investors willing to fund big infrastructure projects at a low or modest cost
of capital, eg pension funds and sovereign wealth funds, demand secure revenue
streams that markets on their own will not provide. This necessarily implies
either government guarantee in some form, or some equivalent in terms of
monopoly status and mandated moves towards low carbon. (This argument is
explored in more depth on another page on this site).
5. Effective
strategy is highly dependent on innovation, and the market failures related to
innovation are well documented. Again this implies significant interventions as
well as price signals that incentivise investment.
6. There are
numerous instances where regulation on its own can achieve significant gains.
One of the most dramatic illustrations of this is the effect of the change in
US road vehicle regulation, in the late 1980s, relaxing the Corporate Average
Fuel Efficiency (CAFE) standards for vehicle fuel efficiency. Technical
progress in engine efficiency, implying a falling consumption per tonne, but
without the CAFE targets the efficiency gain simply translated into heavier (ie
more wasteful in energy terms) vehicles, and vehicle fuel efficiency
improvement came to an end.
Trends in engine efficiency
contrasted with trends in vehicle fuel economy, responding to relaxation of
US Corporate Average Fuel Economy (CAFE) standards in late 1980s. Source;
Lutsey and Sperling.
|
The reality is that effective progress
depends on a fusion of the two camps. The propositions are not mutually
exclusive but mutually reinforcing. Many of the “other leading greenhouse gas
emitting countries”, to whom the proposals are to be put, have long recognised
(as has the World Bank) that a trio of policy instruments is required.
·
Markets and taxes are the instruments with which economists are most at
home, framed to reflect the massive externalities of future environmental
damage that are not captured without an intervention of the kind proposed by
the US economists.
·
Innovation and infrastructure, which for the most part are only
partly and insufficiently incentivised by market signals, and usually depend
heavily on additional intervention with some form of government support and
(typically) financial or regulatory guarantees.
·
Regulations and standards which only governments can enforce, to
support policy objectives and promote behavioural change where that is
part of the solution.
[1] Helm
D, Hepburn C, Ruta G (2012) Trade, climate change, and the political game
theory of border carbon adjustments. Oxford Review of Economic Policy, 28:
368-394.
[2] This
is discussed at much greater length in the author’s earlier paper. Cumulative
Carbon Emissions And Climate Change: Has The Economics Of Climate Policies Lost
Contact With The Physics?, John
Rhys, OIES Working Paper EV 57, July 2011.
[3] The
“Green Paradox” is usually attributed to a controversial book by German
economist, Hans-Werner Sinn, describing the observation that policies
that becomes greener with the passage of time acts like an expressed intention
to expropriate fossil resources for the owners, inducing them to accelerate extraction
and hence to accentuate the problems.
No comments:
Post a Comment